A ‘Gap-Filling’ Book on Islamic Economic Thought
This
book is a collection of previously-published papers on the origins of
economic thought discovered in the writings of some prominent Islamic
scholars belonging to the five centuries prior to the pre-modern era.
This period was labelled by the late Joseph Schumpeter in the 1950s as
representing the "great gap" in literary history, in particular the
history of economic thought. Since then, this mishap, already well
embedded in the relevant literature, was further strengthened and
perpetuated. However, during this period the Islamic civilisation was
about the most fertile grounds for intellectual developments in various
disciplines, including economics. The present single-volume collection
of papers attempts to fill that blind-spot in the history of economic
thought.
Table of contents
1. Setting the stage
2. Challenging the 'Great Gap' thesis
3. Extracts from the book
3.1. Foreword by Professor S. Todd Lowry
3.2. Introduction by Professor S.M. Ghazanfar
4. Table of Contents
5. References and further reading on economic thought in Islam: past and present
Review of Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the 'Great Gap' in European Economics,
edited by S.M. Ghazanfar; Foreword by S. Todd Lowry. Book Series:
"Islamic Studies Series". London/New York: Routledge/Curzon, 2003. xv +
284 pp. (hardback), ISBN: 0-415-29778-8. Paperback 2007. ISBN-10:
0415444519, ISBN-13: 978-0415444514, 22.9 x 15.5 x 2.3 cm.
1. Setting the stage
The resurgence of various studies in recent decades on the history of socio-economic thought, focusing on the writings of various medieval Islamic scholars (e.g., Al-Ghazali, Ibn Taimiyah, Ibn Qayyim, and others), is a noteworthy progress in social sciences. This literature challenges the "great gap" thesis propounded by the late Joseph Schumpeter. This thesis argued that the centuries between the Greeks and the medieval Latin-scholastics were "blank," during which nothing of significance to economics was written anywhere. On the contrary, what emerged in recent scholarship is a totally different image. During this period several Islamic scholars wrote extensively on economics topics. Their writings, as those of their Latin-European successors, were teleological and holistic, with salvation as the ultimate purpose, but they include nevertheless significant positive content, and their discussion on numerous economic topics is remarkably similar to that found in contemporary literature. However, the mainstream literature completely omits their contributions; and, despite Schumpter's insistence on "filiation and continuity of ideas," his "gap" is thoroughly entrenched in the profession.
The book Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the 'Great Gap' in European Economics, edited by S.M. Ghazanfar, explores the field and seeks to contribute to a dialogue of mutual understanding, appreciation, and accommodation. Further, it attempts to fill the "great gap" in literary history. While only a few early Muslim scholars are included and the period covered is chiefly the Schumpeterian "blank centuries," obviously there were others during the same period and others beyond that period (e.g., Ibn Khaldun, 1342-1405) who wrote on economic issues; some wrote even separate treatise on economic matters. Beginning with the introductory essay that ignited the challenge, the book includes fifteen papers covering the works of several Muslim scholars. Themes discussed in their writings include, the functioning of the market mechanism in Islam before Adam Smith, economics of public finance in early Islamic writings, linkages and parallels between the economics of al-Ghazali and St. Thomas Aquinas, social thought of some early Muslim scholars and their influence on Latin-Europe, etc.
2. Challenging the 'Great Gap' thesis
The book under review challenges the conventional wisdom deeply
entrenched in contemporary social sciences as to literary history and
the origins of socio-economic thought. Concepts such as "rationality"
and "progress" have been made exclusive to western contributions to
human civilisation. As such, Europe and the West are assigned the unique
position (quite erroneously, to be sure) of having evolved literary
history in almost all its dimensions, leading to Enlightenment and
Renaissance, and dynamic forces that resulted in 17th-century Scientific
Revolution. At the same time, the non-European world is viewed as
static, irrational, backwards, and basically "history-less".
This paradigm disregards the rest of the world when it comes to considering the progression of the ideas critical to the evolution of all human societies. Basically, it has been taken so much for granted that only "The West" has had any impact on "history" and "rational thought" and "knowledge" have been viewed as almost the exclusive domain of the Western mind.
In this context, Joseph Schumpeter, the Austro-American economist propounded the "great gap" thesis, arguing that between the collapse of the Greco-Roman civilisation and the dawn of the Enlightenment (the period generally identified as the European "Dark Ages"), no significant socio-economic thought or literary progression ever took place. He argued that "economic analysis begins with the Greeks," not to be re-established until the Latin-Scholastics emerged with St. Thomas Aquinas (1225-1274)—the intervening centuries were simply "blank." Such a thesis ignores any contribution of the rest of the world to the history of economic thought and overlooks the numerous writings left by scholars from the early Islamic civilization in particular, but also from the Byzantine, Chinese, and Indian traditions.
Since the world we live in now is pretty much defined by the economic
successes of Europe and the West in the last two centuries (post
Industrial Revolution), then it was never seen as necessary or possible
to dispute the Schumpeterian thesis, like other Eurocentric ideas in the
realm of culture or religion has been. It is in this context that
Professor Ghazanfar's book is so original. It is an attempt to show that
the aforementioned paradigm is patently absurd. Thus, the main
objective of the book is to demonstrate, with well-documented evidence,
that within the world of North Africa and West Asia, not only was
economic activity (albeit in its non-European, non-Industrial form)
alive and well, but so was economic thought in its various dimensions.
By exploring and documenting the works of scholars who influenced the
course of economic events and thought in this region and even directly
influenced numerous medieval European minds (particularly the
ecclesiastical and secular thinkers such as Aquinas or Bacon), Ghazanfar
attempts to bring in ample examples of economic forces (from those
designed to regulate the market to the relationship between
private-sector economic activities and the role of the public sector) in
order to show that the "great gap" was not present in the world to the
south and east of the Mediterranean. In this, he is remarkably
successful and is further assisted by auxiliary and complementary
articles describing the situation in the Islamic lands beyond the
Mediterranean environ. Some debates and discussions are also included,
broadening the conversation to include more than a few issues particular
to the world of medieval Islam. However, the fact that the book is an
edited volume of several independently-written articles, each requiring
its own introduction and narrative, the book tends to become a bit
repetitive towards the end, although these parts can be easily escaped
when they are absorbed properly from the earlier articles.
While the focus of the book, Medieval Islamic Economic Thought,
is primarily on economic thought originating in the writings of several
medieval Muslim scholars, it also documents the multi-dimensional
influences from the early Islamic civilization which gave rise to an
unprecedented intellectual revival in Latin-Europe. Economic ideas of a
few early Islamic scholars are documented and it is argued that these
ideas are remarkably similar to those found in contemporary textbooks,
though not as elegantly presented. For example, Abu Hamid al-Ghazali
discussed the notions of specialization and division of labour in the
early 11th century, something that is usually attributed to Adam Smith's
Wealth of Nations (1776).
Further, one finds discussion of incentives-based free-enterprise, voluntary-exchange economy, demand and supply forces and their intensities, production efficiency, stages of production, hierarchy of consumption needs, environmental concerns, poverty and income distribution, social welfare optimization, role of money (including currency debasement, counterfeiting), regional trade, public finances (including various types of taxes and their incentive-equity effects), elements of cost-benefits analysis, role of the state, regulation of markets, role of a market regulator (the muhtasib), etc. Indeed, the essential roots of modern capitalism lie in the early Islamic world.
3. Extracts from the book
3.1. Foreword by Professor S. Todd Lowry
"The Anglo-American intellectual tradition focuses on the north
European Atlantic-oriented societies during their cultural development
over the last few centuries. This is particularly true of the history of
economic thought. The consolidation of nation states and the growth of
international commerce in England, France, the Low Countries, and the
Hanseatic cities during the 16th and 17th centuries provided the
foundations for the agricultural and industrial revolutions of the 18th
and early 19th centuries. It is not surprising, therefore, that the
classic paradigm in economic thought, set out in J.A. Schumpeter's
erudite History of Economic Analysis in 1954, concentrated on
the thought of this period with an emphasis on the "Great Gap" between
the philosophical contributions of ancient Greece and their rediscovery
in the Middle Ages. The interval between the intellectual culture of
antiquity and its north European "rebirth" or Renaissance has been
labelled the "Dark Ages" from a north European idiosyncratic
perspective. Professor S.M. Ghazanfar has formally challenged this
mindset, the "Great Gap" thesis that was emphasized by Schumpeter.
"The historical facts are undeniable, namely that the culture of antiquity was sustained and developed in the Islamic world during the medieval period; and the intellectual darkness in northern Europe from the 7th to the 11th century AD was a strictly local phenomenon. The torchbearers of ancient learning during the medieval period were the Muslims, and it was from them that the Renaissance was sparked and the Enlightenment kindled. This has been amply demonstrated in the history of science and mathematics in recent years. For example, in the early 12th century, the Englishman Adelard of Bath travelled to Muslim Spain and Syria, collecting and translating Arabic manuscripts on mathematics. He is credited with bringing Euclid's Elements into the medieval academic world. What has been generally ignored, however, is the character and sophistication of Arabic writings on economic subjects.
"The Muslim Scholastics oriented much of their work in terms of
theological discourse, as did the Christian schoolmen. The number of
these Christian writers that were able to read Arabic is little noted
and the parallels between Muslim and Christian writings have yet to be
definitively drawn. We can observe, however, for illustrative purposes,
that the Scholastic doctrine of Lucrum Cessans or A Value Conceded,
used by Christian theologians to justify the charging of a price to
cover lost income resulting from the lending of money (opportunity
cost), was a Muslim doctrine dating from early medieval times, according
to Maxime Rodinson's Islam and Capitalism (1978). The influence of Aristotelianism as characterized by Louis Baeck in his The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought
(1994) was primarily moral. The Muslim Scholastics, preceding the
Christian schoolmen, also couched their writings in moral or religious
terms. They were, however, primarily dealing with practical issues of
the day in the idiom of their culture. Yassine Essid, in his A Critique of the Origins of Islamic Economic Thought (1995), has described the administrative orientation of the institution of the muhtasib,
or ombudsman, or market manager and judge. The manuals that provided
guidance and instruction for his conduct give us a clear picture of the
economy of the Muslim city. This official was in charge of weights and
measures as well as standards of fairness and quality that are
preconditions for the functioning of markets. Regulations varied with
the need to protect the public and the economic health of the city from
forces that would limit the fair balance of trade or take advantage of
shortages of necessary consumer goods. This tradition was carried into
Muslim Spain with the institution of El Señor del Suq, or master of the market. The Arabic word for market, suq, is preserved in modern Spanish as zoco or zocolo meaning central market or plaza.
"It was an Islamic principle not to set prices for the market, but, by the same token, there was no equivalent to the 18th-century belief in natural order emerging from the market. The market regulators could set maximum and minimum prices for goods and had elaborate rules illustrating the need to protect a zone of fair bargaining from a very sophisticated capacity for mercantile fraud. Requiring similar crafts and traders to be aggregated in separate sections of the market promoted competition and comparative shopping. Close supervision of weights and measures and quality also supported the market function. Once when a Tunisian friend came into my office, I was apprised of an old Arabic epithet when he commented, "This place looks like a suq!"--a jumbled mess. It is in this context that we must approach Professor Ghazanfar's interest in the economic writings of the Muslim theologians and the parallels with their Christian cohorts. Not only were the Muslim commercial towns of Spain and north Africa more sophisticated and better managed than the nascent towns of 11th- and 12th-century Europe, excepting Italy, but the European Scholastics and mathematicians looked to the Muslim world for their intellectual progress, as did the merchants. The Greek classics, particularly Aristotle's work, were accessible through translations from the Arabic. The strength of the commercial culture of the Mediterranean during the Middle Ages has been somewhat ignored and brushed aside by the idiosyncratic nationalism of the Atlantic states. We have forgotten the trade languages, Lingua Franca in the eastern Mediterranean and Saber in the western Mediterranean, and the academic contacts between Cordoba and Paris. When, in the 13th century, the English sought to protect their small farmers from cattle theft and untrustworthy continental cattle buyers, they established special market towns with specific market days. The market rules prohibited forestalling, engrossing and regrating. Forestalling was buying from a farmer en route to the market with cajoling stories of collapsed prices, etc. It also meant that sales had to take place in the open market to be legal. In this way stolen cattle could be identified. It is hardly an accident that these three restrictions existed in the Muslim market rules with similar definitions (Essid, 155-7). As the "less developed" countries--France, the Netherlands and England--took up an active commercial life, it makes sense for us to look at their intellectual and practical evolution as an extension of the Mediterranean experience.
"The eminent analyst of medieval Scholasticism, Odd Langholm, in his recent book The Legacy of Scholasticism in Economic Thought (1998), brings out the institutional practicalities of Scholastic policy and theory. This same perspective on the relation between Muslim and Christian Scholasticism is in order and is a badly needed step toward a proper understanding of the influence of the superior Muslim scientific and philosophical erudition of medieval times. Not only can it be documented that many scientists and theologians in the medieval period read Arabic, it is strange that St Thomas Aquinas' embrace of Aristotelianism has seldom been correlated with a familiarity with Muslim academic erudition, since Aristotle's works were being drawn from Muslim intermediaries. Aquinas was raised in Naples, in the shadow of the then cultural sophistication of the Court of Frederick II in Sicily. Professor Ghazanfar has the study of Aquinas' Arabic sources.
"Furthermore, it is well known that the work of Averroes (Ibn Rushd) and Avicenna (Ibn Sina) were dominant influences in the School of Paris. It is, therefore, high time for extensive study of the Muslim literature of the time as the basis for a broader perspective on our theoretical heritage and the history of our economic customs and practices. It is seldom noted that our word cheque for a financial instrument comes from an Arabic term, and that our word magazine for storage room or literary collection comes from the Arabic word for warehouse".
3.2. Introduction by Professor S.M. Ghazanfar
"While the 9/11 apocalyptic nightmare and subsequent events have generated an environment in which academic discussions of the "civilizational clash" vis-à-vis the West and the Islamic world have surfaced to the common consciousness, this very phenomenon also suggests the intense need for a dialogue across cultures and nations. That indeed was the spirit behind the 1998 United Nations resolution which declared 2001 as the "Year of Civilizational Dialogue". While the present volume focuses primarily on economic thought in the writings of several medieval Islamic scholars, it also documents the multi-dimensional linkages and influences, extending over several medieval centuries, between the then vibrant Islamic civilization and the evolving Latin-European culture. In that sense, this book may make some modest contribution toward cultivating the spirit of dialogue and appreciation of inexorable historic connections between the two worlds whose origins lie in the same crucible.
"The book is a single-volume collection of papers, published during recent years in various national and international journals, on the subject of the origins of economic thought among medieval Islamic Scholastics; this is not a book about Islamic economics, however. A key stimulus for these papers emanates from a blind spot that has long prevailed in the relevant literature and which was further strengthened and perpetuated by the late Joseph A. Schumpeter. In his classic History of Economic Analysis (1954), Schumpeter propounded the "Great Gap" thesis, namely that the several centuries between the Greeks and the Latin Scholastics (particularly St Thomas Aquinas, 1225-74) were simply "blank" centuries (Schumpeter, 74). During this period, argued Schumpeter, nothing of relevance to economics was written anywhere (nor was anything written, it would seem, in any other discipline) (Schumpeter, 52). Such a claim is patently untenable, as argued in Chapter 1 of this volume.
"Unfortunately, however, the "gap" tradition is well entrenched in almost all relevant literature-indeed, in almost all literary history. The li terature on economic ideas, often presented as "universal", "comprehensive" and "international in scope", almost invariably begins with Aristotle (384-322BC), then leaps to St Thomas Aquinas and beyond, but is restricted to European/North American scholarship. Despite his insistence on "intellectual continuity" and "filiation of ideas", Schumpeter chose to disregard the contributions from other civilizations and cultures, in particular the contributions of medieval Islamic writers. Almost precisely during this period, the Islamic civilization represented about the most fertile environment of intellectual activity in almost all areas of then known endeavours, including socio-economic thought. With the background of the rediscovered Greek intellectual reservoir, numerous Islamic scholars developed concepts and notions on various economic topics, among other things, which are remarkably similar, though less elegantly couched, to those found in the writings of subsequent European scholars as well as in the contemporary literature; some Islamic sages even wrote separate treatises specifically devoted to economic/commercial issues. Further, almost all of this intellectual output was transferred en masse, through various sources and over several centuries, to early Latin-Europe. And this knowledge transfer facilitated the 12th-century Renaissance, with its emphasis on science and philosophy, and laid the foundations for "the Protestant Reformation in the 16th century and eventually the rise of modern science in the seventeenth" (Nebelsick, 9). Indeed, this was the period when "Islam was at one and the same time the enemy and the great source of higher material and intellectual culture" (Watt 1965, 180).
"While the blind spot of the Schumpeterian literature "gap" persists in much of the mainstream literature, there is evidence of some recent accommodative gestures. The 1994 History of Economics Society conference commemorated the 50th anniversary of Schumpeter's classic, and it included sessions on the "gap" thesis (the lead paper, "Post-Greek/pre-Renaissance economic thought", is included in the present volume). Subsequently, several papers from this conference were published in an edited volume, and in referring to the "gap" controversy, the editor says: 'of all Schumpeter's alleged errors in the HEA, the one that seems to have stirred up the most debate among historians is Schumpeter's remark about the alleged "Great Gap" in the flow of analytic discussions between the 9th and 14th centuries' (Moss 1996b, 5).
And he further points out:
'Thanks to the research presented… and to a variety of important other writings and papers… as this century ends, historians can celebrate some success in responding to Schumpeter's implicit challenge…' ((ibid., 7)".
4. Table of Contents
Notes on Contributors
S. Todd Lowry Foreword
Acknowledgements
Index
Contributors Information
1. Setting the stage
2. Challenging the 'Great Gap' thesis
3. Extracts from the book
3.1. Foreword by Professor S. Todd Lowry
3.2. Introduction by Professor S.M. Ghazanfar
4. Table of Contents
5. References and further reading on economic thought in Islam: past and present
Figure 1: Front cover of Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the 'Great Gap' in European Economics, edited by S.M. Ghazanfar (Routledge and Curzon, 2003).
|
1. Setting the stage
The resurgence of various studies in recent decades on the history of socio-economic thought, focusing on the writings of various medieval Islamic scholars (e.g., Al-Ghazali, Ibn Taimiyah, Ibn Qayyim, and others), is a noteworthy progress in social sciences. This literature challenges the "great gap" thesis propounded by the late Joseph Schumpeter. This thesis argued that the centuries between the Greeks and the medieval Latin-scholastics were "blank," during which nothing of significance to economics was written anywhere. On the contrary, what emerged in recent scholarship is a totally different image. During this period several Islamic scholars wrote extensively on economics topics. Their writings, as those of their Latin-European successors, were teleological and holistic, with salvation as the ultimate purpose, but they include nevertheless significant positive content, and their discussion on numerous economic topics is remarkably similar to that found in contemporary literature. However, the mainstream literature completely omits their contributions; and, despite Schumpter's insistence on "filiation and continuity of ideas," his "gap" is thoroughly entrenched in the profession.
The book Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the 'Great Gap' in European Economics, edited by S.M. Ghazanfar, explores the field and seeks to contribute to a dialogue of mutual understanding, appreciation, and accommodation. Further, it attempts to fill the "great gap" in literary history. While only a few early Muslim scholars are included and the period covered is chiefly the Schumpeterian "blank centuries," obviously there were others during the same period and others beyond that period (e.g., Ibn Khaldun, 1342-1405) who wrote on economic issues; some wrote even separate treatise on economic matters. Beginning with the introductory essay that ignited the challenge, the book includes fifteen papers covering the works of several Muslim scholars. Themes discussed in their writings include, the functioning of the market mechanism in Islam before Adam Smith, economics of public finance in early Islamic writings, linkages and parallels between the economics of al-Ghazali and St. Thomas Aquinas, social thought of some early Muslim scholars and their influence on Latin-Europe, etc.
2. Challenging the 'Great Gap' thesis
Figure 2: Manuscript of al-Ghazali's al-Tabr al-Masbuk fi Nasihat al-Muluk wa al-Wuzara wa al-Wulat at the Ameican University in Beirut (Source).
|
This paradigm disregards the rest of the world when it comes to considering the progression of the ideas critical to the evolution of all human societies. Basically, it has been taken so much for granted that only "The West" has had any impact on "history" and "rational thought" and "knowledge" have been viewed as almost the exclusive domain of the Western mind.
In this context, Joseph Schumpeter, the Austro-American economist propounded the "great gap" thesis, arguing that between the collapse of the Greco-Roman civilisation and the dawn of the Enlightenment (the period generally identified as the European "Dark Ages"), no significant socio-economic thought or literary progression ever took place. He argued that "economic analysis begins with the Greeks," not to be re-established until the Latin-Scholastics emerged with St. Thomas Aquinas (1225-1274)—the intervening centuries were simply "blank." Such a thesis ignores any contribution of the rest of the world to the history of economic thought and overlooks the numerous writings left by scholars from the early Islamic civilization in particular, but also from the Byzantine, Chinese, and Indian traditions.
Figure 3: Map of the Silk road and the Arab trade sea route (Source).
|
Figure 4: Islamic coins of
the Abbadis period (Caliph Harun al-Rashid, r. 170-193 H/786-809 CE).
Dirhams, script on each side "Madinat-al-Salaam mint", dated 190 H (Source).
|
Further, one finds discussion of incentives-based free-enterprise, voluntary-exchange economy, demand and supply forces and their intensities, production efficiency, stages of production, hierarchy of consumption needs, environmental concerns, poverty and income distribution, social welfare optimization, role of money (including currency debasement, counterfeiting), regional trade, public finances (including various types of taxes and their incentive-equity effects), elements of cost-benefits analysis, role of the state, regulation of markets, role of a market regulator (the muhtasib), etc. Indeed, the essential roots of modern capitalism lie in the early Islamic world.
3. Extracts from the book
3.1. Foreword by Professor S. Todd Lowry
Figure 5: Front cover of The Bazaar: Markets and Merchants of the Islamic World by Walter M. Weiss, Kurt-Michael Westermann (Thames & Hudson, 1998).
|
"The historical facts are undeniable, namely that the culture of antiquity was sustained and developed in the Islamic world during the medieval period; and the intellectual darkness in northern Europe from the 7th to the 11th century AD was a strictly local phenomenon. The torchbearers of ancient learning during the medieval period were the Muslims, and it was from them that the Renaissance was sparked and the Enlightenment kindled. This has been amply demonstrated in the history of science and mathematics in recent years. For example, in the early 12th century, the Englishman Adelard of Bath travelled to Muslim Spain and Syria, collecting and translating Arabic manuscripts on mathematics. He is credited with bringing Euclid's Elements into the medieval academic world. What has been generally ignored, however, is the character and sophistication of Arabic writings on economic subjects.
Figure 6: The Egyptian Bazaar in Istanbul (2007) (Source).
|
"It was an Islamic principle not to set prices for the market, but, by the same token, there was no equivalent to the 18th-century belief in natural order emerging from the market. The market regulators could set maximum and minimum prices for goods and had elaborate rules illustrating the need to protect a zone of fair bargaining from a very sophisticated capacity for mercantile fraud. Requiring similar crafts and traders to be aggregated in separate sections of the market promoted competition and comparative shopping. Close supervision of weights and measures and quality also supported the market function. Once when a Tunisian friend came into my office, I was apprised of an old Arabic epithet when he commented, "This place looks like a suq!"--a jumbled mess. It is in this context that we must approach Professor Ghazanfar's interest in the economic writings of the Muslim theologians and the parallels with their Christian cohorts. Not only were the Muslim commercial towns of Spain and north Africa more sophisticated and better managed than the nascent towns of 11th- and 12th-century Europe, excepting Italy, but the European Scholastics and mathematicians looked to the Muslim world for their intellectual progress, as did the merchants. The Greek classics, particularly Aristotle's work, were accessible through translations from the Arabic. The strength of the commercial culture of the Mediterranean during the Middle Ages has been somewhat ignored and brushed aside by the idiosyncratic nationalism of the Atlantic states. We have forgotten the trade languages, Lingua Franca in the eastern Mediterranean and Saber in the western Mediterranean, and the academic contacts between Cordoba and Paris. When, in the 13th century, the English sought to protect their small farmers from cattle theft and untrustworthy continental cattle buyers, they established special market towns with specific market days. The market rules prohibited forestalling, engrossing and regrating. Forestalling was buying from a farmer en route to the market with cajoling stories of collapsed prices, etc. It also meant that sales had to take place in the open market to be legal. In this way stolen cattle could be identified. It is hardly an accident that these three restrictions existed in the Muslim market rules with similar definitions (Essid, 155-7). As the "less developed" countries--France, the Netherlands and England--took up an active commercial life, it makes sense for us to look at their intellectual and practical evolution as an extension of the Mediterranean experience.
"The eminent analyst of medieval Scholasticism, Odd Langholm, in his recent book The Legacy of Scholasticism in Economic Thought (1998), brings out the institutional practicalities of Scholastic policy and theory. This same perspective on the relation between Muslim and Christian Scholasticism is in order and is a badly needed step toward a proper understanding of the influence of the superior Muslim scientific and philosophical erudition of medieval times. Not only can it be documented that many scientists and theologians in the medieval period read Arabic, it is strange that St Thomas Aquinas' embrace of Aristotelianism has seldom been correlated with a familiarity with Muslim academic erudition, since Aristotle's works were being drawn from Muslim intermediaries. Aquinas was raised in Naples, in the shadow of the then cultural sophistication of the Court of Frederick II in Sicily. Professor Ghazanfar has the study of Aquinas' Arabic sources.
"Furthermore, it is well known that the work of Averroes (Ibn Rushd) and Avicenna (Ibn Sina) were dominant influences in the School of Paris. It is, therefore, high time for extensive study of the Muslim literature of the time as the basis for a broader perspective on our theoretical heritage and the history of our economic customs and practices. It is seldom noted that our word cheque for a financial instrument comes from an Arabic term, and that our word magazine for storage room or literary collection comes from the Arabic word for warehouse".
3.2. Introduction by Professor S.M. Ghazanfar
"While the 9/11 apocalyptic nightmare and subsequent events have generated an environment in which academic discussions of the "civilizational clash" vis-à-vis the West and the Islamic world have surfaced to the common consciousness, this very phenomenon also suggests the intense need for a dialogue across cultures and nations. That indeed was the spirit behind the 1998 United Nations resolution which declared 2001 as the "Year of Civilizational Dialogue". While the present volume focuses primarily on economic thought in the writings of several medieval Islamic scholars, it also documents the multi-dimensional linkages and influences, extending over several medieval centuries, between the then vibrant Islamic civilization and the evolving Latin-European culture. In that sense, this book may make some modest contribution toward cultivating the spirit of dialogue and appreciation of inexorable historic connections between the two worlds whose origins lie in the same crucible.
"The book is a single-volume collection of papers, published during recent years in various national and international journals, on the subject of the origins of economic thought among medieval Islamic Scholastics; this is not a book about Islamic economics, however. A key stimulus for these papers emanates from a blind spot that has long prevailed in the relevant literature and which was further strengthened and perpetuated by the late Joseph A. Schumpeter. In his classic History of Economic Analysis (1954), Schumpeter propounded the "Great Gap" thesis, namely that the several centuries between the Greeks and the Latin Scholastics (particularly St Thomas Aquinas, 1225-74) were simply "blank" centuries (Schumpeter, 74). During this period, argued Schumpeter, nothing of relevance to economics was written anywhere (nor was anything written, it would seem, in any other discipline) (Schumpeter, 52). Such a claim is patently untenable, as argued in Chapter 1 of this volume.
"Unfortunately, however, the "gap" tradition is well entrenched in almost all relevant literature-indeed, in almost all literary history. The li terature on economic ideas, often presented as "universal", "comprehensive" and "international in scope", almost invariably begins with Aristotle (384-322BC), then leaps to St Thomas Aquinas and beyond, but is restricted to European/North American scholarship. Despite his insistence on "intellectual continuity" and "filiation of ideas", Schumpeter chose to disregard the contributions from other civilizations and cultures, in particular the contributions of medieval Islamic writers. Almost precisely during this period, the Islamic civilization represented about the most fertile environment of intellectual activity in almost all areas of then known endeavours, including socio-economic thought. With the background of the rediscovered Greek intellectual reservoir, numerous Islamic scholars developed concepts and notions on various economic topics, among other things, which are remarkably similar, though less elegantly couched, to those found in the writings of subsequent European scholars as well as in the contemporary literature; some Islamic sages even wrote separate treatises specifically devoted to economic/commercial issues. Further, almost all of this intellectual output was transferred en masse, through various sources and over several centuries, to early Latin-Europe. And this knowledge transfer facilitated the 12th-century Renaissance, with its emphasis on science and philosophy, and laid the foundations for "the Protestant Reformation in the 16th century and eventually the rise of modern science in the seventeenth" (Nebelsick, 9). Indeed, this was the period when "Islam was at one and the same time the enemy and the great source of higher material and intellectual culture" (Watt 1965, 180).
"While the blind spot of the Schumpeterian literature "gap" persists in much of the mainstream literature, there is evidence of some recent accommodative gestures. The 1994 History of Economics Society conference commemorated the 50th anniversary of Schumpeter's classic, and it included sessions on the "gap" thesis (the lead paper, "Post-Greek/pre-Renaissance economic thought", is included in the present volume). Subsequently, several papers from this conference were published in an edited volume, and in referring to the "gap" controversy, the editor says: 'of all Schumpeter's alleged errors in the HEA, the one that seems to have stirred up the most debate among historians is Schumpeter's remark about the alleged "Great Gap" in the flow of analytic discussions between the 9th and 14th centuries' (Moss 1996b, 5).
And he further points out:
'Thanks to the research presented… and to a variety of important other writings and papers… as this century ends, historians can celebrate some success in responding to Schumpeter's implicit challenge…' ((ibid., 7)".
4. Table of Contents
Notes on Contributors
S. Todd Lowry Foreword
Acknowledgements
- S.M. Ghazanfar, Scholastic Economics and Arab Scholars: The "Great Gap" Thesis Reconsidered (originally published, in seven languages, Diogenese: International Review of Humane Studies, Paris, no.154, April-June 1991)
- S.M. Ghazanfar and A. Azim Islahi Economic Thought of an Arab Scholastic: Abu-hamid Al-Ghazali (ah450-505/1058-1111ad) (originally published, History of Political Economy, vol.22, no.2, 1990)
- Paul Oslington, Economic Thought and Religious Thought, A Comment on Ghazanfar and Islahi (originally published, History of Political Economy, vol.27, no.4, 1995)
- S.M. Ghazanfar and A. Azim Islahi, A Rejoinder to "Economic Thought and Religious Thought" (originally published, History of Political Economy, vol.27, no.4, 1995)
- S.M. Ghazanfar and A. Azim Islahi, Explorations in Medieval Arab-islamic Economic Thought: Some Aspects of Ibn Taimiyah's Economics (originally published, S. Todd Lowry, Editor, Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought: Selected Papers from the History of Economic Thought Conference 1990, vol.7, Edward Elgar, Vermont, 1992)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, History of Economic Thought: The Schumpeterian "Great Gap", The "lost" Arab-Islamic Legacy and The Literature gap (originally published, Journal of Islamic Studies (Oxford), vol.6, no.2, 1995)
- Hamid Hosseini, Understanding The Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam (originally published, History of Political Economy, vol.27, no.3, 1995)
- Hamid Hosseini, Innaccuracy of The Schumpeterian "Great Gap" Thesis: Economic Thought in Medieval Iran (Persia) (originally published, Laurence S. Moss, Editor, Joseph A. Schumpeter, Historian of Economics: Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought—Selected Papers from the History of Economics Society Conference 1994, Routledge, London and New York, 1996)
- S.M. Ghazanfar and A. Azim Islahi, Explorations in Medieval Arab-Islamic Economic Thought: Some Aspects of Ibn Qayyim's Economics (ah691-751/1292-1350ad) (originally published, History of Economic Ideas (Italy), vol.3, no.1, 1997)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, Medieval Islamic Socio-economic Thought: Links With Greek and Latin-European Scholarship (originally published, Humanomics, vol.13, nos.3-4, 1997)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, Post-Greek/pre-Rrenaissance Economic Thought: Contributions of Arab-islamic Scholastics During The "Great Gap" Centuries (originally published, Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, no.16, 1998)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, The Economic Thought of Abu Hamid Al-Ghazali and St Thomas Aquinas: Some Comparative Parallels and Links (originally published, History of Political Economy, vol.34, no.2, 2000)
- M. Nejatullah Siddiqi and S.M. Ghazanfar, Early Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Abu Yousuf's (731-798ad) Economics of Public Finance (originally published, History of Economic Ideas (Italy), vol.9, no.1, 2001)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, Public-sector Economics in Medieval Economic Thought: Contributions of Selected Arab-Islamic Scholars (originally published, Public Finance/Finances Publiques, vo.53, no.1, 1998)
- S.M. Ghazanfar, Medieval Social Thought European Renaissance: The Influence of Selected Arab-Islamic Scholastics (presented, International Medieval Congress 2001, University of Leeds, U.K., 2001; modified version published, Encounters: Journal of Intercultural Perspectives (UK), vol.9, no.1, 2003)
Index
Contributors Information
- S.M. Ghazanfar, University of Idaho, USA
- Hamid Hosseini, King's College, Pennsylvania, USA
- A. Azim Islahi, Aligarh Muslim University, India
- S. Todd Lowry, Washington & Lee University, Virginia, USA
- Paul Oslington, University of New South Wales, Australia
- M. Nejatullah Siddiqi, University of California, Los Angeles, USA
- Ahmed, Ehsan, ed., International Islamic Economics Seminar: Economic growth and human resource development in an Islamic perspective. Proceedings of the Fourth International Islamic Economics Seminar, (4th, 1992, Washington, D.C.). Herndon, Va., U.S.A.: Jointly published by the Association of Muslim Social Scientists and the International Institute of Islamic Thought, 1993.
- Ali, S. Nazim, "Information on Islamic Banking and Economics as Represented by Selected Databases". International journal of information management, vol. 13, No. 3:205 (June 1993).
- Ali, Syed Nazim, Information sources on Islamic banking and economics, 1980-1990. London; New York: Kegan Paul International; distributed by John Wiley & Sons, 1994.
- Ariff, Mohamed, ed. Islamic banking in Southeast Asia: Islam and the economic development of Southeast Asia. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, ca. 1988.
- Ariff, Mohamed, ed., Islam and the economic development of Southeast Asia: the Muslim private sector in Southeast Asia. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, ca. 1991.
- Ariff, Mohamed, ed., The Islamic voluntary sector in Southeast Asia: Islam and the economic development of Southeast Asia. Pasir Panjang, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, ca. 1991.
- Baeck, Louis, "The economic thought of classical Islam. (Arab-Muslim Contributions to Political Economic Thought)". Diogenes, n ° 154 (Summer, 1991):99 (17 pages).
- Chapra, Muhammad Umer, Islam and economic development: a strategy for development with justice and stability. Islamabad, Pakistan: International Institute of Islamic Thought: Islamic Research Institute, 1993.
- Chapra, Muhammad Umer, Islam and the economic challenge. Leicester, U.K.: Islamic Foundation; Herndon, VA: International Institute of Islamic Thought, ca. 1992.
- Chaudhry, Muhammad Sharif, Taxation in Islam and modern taxes. 1st ed. Lahore: Impact Publication International, 1992.
- Choudhury, Masudul Alam, Contributions to Islamic economic theory: a study in social economics. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1986.
- Choudhury, Masudul Alam, The principles of Islamic political economy: a methodological enquiry. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1992.
- Essid, Yassine, A critique of the origins of Islamic economic thought. Leiden; New York: E.J. Brill, 1995.
- Fahim Khan, M., Essays in Islamic economics. Leicester, England: Islamic Foundation, ca. 1995.
- Gambling, Trevor, and Rifaat Ahmed Abdel Karim, Business and accounting ethics in Islam. London; New York: Mansell, 1991.
- Ghazali, Aidit and Syed Omar, eds., Readings in the concept and methodology of Islamic economics. Petaling Jaya, Selangor Darul Ehsan, Malaysia: Pelanduk Publications, ca. 1989.
- Ghazanfar, S.M., "Scholastic economics and Arab scholars: the "Great Gap" thesis reconsidered." Diogenese: International Review of Humane Sciences, Paris, no.154, April-June 1991.
- Ghazanfar, S.M.; Islahi, A. Azim, "Economic thought of an Arab scholastic: Abu Hamid al-Ghazali", History of Political Economy vol. 22 (Summer, 1990):381 (23 pages).
- Gran, Peter, Islamic Roots of Capitalism: Egypt 1760-1840. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1979.
- Gusau, Sule Ahmed, ed., Economic thoughts of seven great Muslim scholars. Sokoto, Nigeria: Printed and bound by Usmanu Danfodiyo University Printing Press, 1991.
- Hasanuz Zaman, Syed Muhammad, Economic functions of an Islamic state: the early experience. Leicester: Islamic Foundation, 1990.
- Houndmills, Jomo K.S., ed., Islamic economic alternatives: critical perspectives and new directions. Basingstoke, Hampshire: Macmillan, 1992.
- Hosseini, Hamid S., "Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap". In: A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Edited by Warren J. Samuels, Jeff E. Biddle and John B. Davis. Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 2003.
- [International Conference], Industrialisation from an Islamic perspective: international conference proceedings. Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia: Institute of Islamic Understanding, Malaysia and Economic Planning Unit, Prime Minister's Dept., 1993.
- [International Conference], International Conference on Islamic Economics (2nd: 1983: Islamabad, Pakistan): Distributive justice and need fulfilment in an Islamic economy. Edited by Munawar Iqbal. Islamabad: International Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic University; Leicester, U.K.: Islamic Foundation, ca. 1988.
- Iqbal, Zubair and Abbas Mirakhor, Islamic Banking. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1987.
- Iqbal, Zubair and Mohammed S. Amerah, Public Finance in Islam. Lahore: Readers Publishers, 1990.
- Iqbal, Munawar, and Wilson, Rodney, eds., Islamic Perspectives on Wealth Creation. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 2006.
- Islahi, Abdul Azim, Economic concepts of Ibn Taimiyah. Leicester: Islamic Foundation, ca. 1988.
- Johansen, Baber, The Islamic law on land tax and rent: the peasants' loss of property rights as interpreted in the Hanafite legal literature of the Mamluk and Ottoman periods. London; New York: Croom Helm; New York: Methuen, ca. 1988.
- Jung, Mahomed Ullah ibn Sarbuland, The administration of justice in Islam; an introduction to the Muslim conception of the state. Introduction by Hamoodur Rahman. New Delhi: Kitab Bhavan, 1986.
- Kahf, Monzer, "The Islamic Economy: An Analytical Study of the Functioning of the Islamic Economic System", The Journal of Research in Islamic Economics, vol. 1, No. 2, 1984, pp. 83-85.
- Khan, Javed Ahmad, ed., Islamic economics and finance: a bibliography. London; New York: Mansell Publishing, 1995.
- Khan, Mehr Muhammad Nawaz, Islamic and other economic systems. Lahore: Islamic Book Service, 1989.
- Khan, Muhammad Akram, Glossary of Islamic economics. London; New York: Mansell, 1990.
- Khan, Muhammad Akram, An introduction to Islamic economics. Islamabad: International Institute of Islamic Thought and Institute of Islamic Studies, 1994.
- Kuran, Timur, "Islamic economics and the Islamic subeconomy". Journal of Economic Perspectives vol 9, (Fall 1995): 155 (19 pages).
- Kuran, Timur, "On the notion of economic justice in contemporary Islamic thought". International Journal of Middle East Studies vol. 21, n° 2 (May, 1989):171 (21 pages).
- Kuran, Timur, "The discontents of Islamic economic morality". American Economic Review v86, n2 (May, 1996):438 (5 pages).
- Maamiry [al-Maamiry], Ahmed Hamoud, Economics in Islam. New Delhi: Lancers Books, 1987.
- Mallat, Chibli, ed., Islamic law and finance. Introduction by W.M. Ballentyne. London; Boston: Graham & Trotman, ca. 1988.
- Mannan, Muhammad Abdul, Islamic economics: theory and practice. Boulder: Westview Press, 1987, ca. 1986.
- Manzoor, Nayyer, Islamic economics: a welfare approach. Karachi: Saad Publications, 1986.
- Masters, Bruce, "The 1850 events in Aleppo: an aftershock of Syria's incorporation into the capitalist world system". International Journal of Middle East Studies vol. 22, n1 (Feb, 1990):3 (18 pages).
- Meenai, Saeed Ahmed, The Islamic Development Bank: a case study of Islamic co-operation. Foreword by H.E. Mohammed Abalkhail. London; New York: K. Paul International; Distributed by Routledge, Chapman, and Hall, 1989.
- Mehmet, Ozay, Islamic identity and development: studies of the Islamic periphery. London; New York: Routledge, ca. 1990.
- Mehmet, Ozay, Islam and economic development: the challenge of modernity. Ottawa: Asian Pacific Research and Resource Centre, Carleton University, [1991].
- Mills, Paul, and Presley, John, "Islamic Finance: Theory and Practice", The Islamic Economic Studies vol. 1&2 (7), October 1999 and April 2000, pp. 137-139.
- Mirakhor, Abbas, "The Muslim Scholars and the History of Economics: A Need for Consideration", The American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, December 1987, pp. 245-287.
- Naqvi, Safeer Reza, History of banking and Islamic laws. Karachi: Hayat Academy, 1993.
- Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, Islam, economics, and society. London; New York: Kegan Paul International; Distributed by Routledge, ca. 1994.
- Naseef, Abdullah Omar, ed., Today's problems, tomorrow's solutions: the future structure of Muslim societies. London; New York: Mansell, 1988.
- Nasr, Seyyed Vali Reza, "Islamic economies: novel perspectives". Middle Eastern Studies vol. 25, (Oct. 1989), 15 pp.
- Naqvi, S.N.H., "Ethics and Economics - an Islamic Synthesis, The Muslim World Book Review, Autumn 1981, pp. 21-26.
- Nebelsick, Harold P., The Renaissance, The Reformation, and the Rise of Science. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 1992.
- Oslington, Paul, "Economic thought and religious thought: a comment on Ghazanfar and Islahi. (Response to S.M. Ghazanfar and A. Azim Islahi on History of Political Economy)", History of Political Economy vol. 27, (Winter, 1995):775 (6 pages).
- Presley, J.R.; Sessions, J.G., "Islamic Economics: The Emergence of a New Paradigm", The economic journal: the quarterly journal of the Royal Economic Society, vol. 104, No. 424 (May 1994): pp. 584-596.
- Sadeq, AbulHasan Muhammad et al., eds., Development and finance in Islam. Petaling Jaya, Selangor, Malaysia: International Islamic University Press, ca. 1991.
- Saeed, Javaid, Islam and modernization: a comparative analysis of Pakistan, Egypt, and Turkey. Westport, Conn: Praeger, 1994.
- Saleh, Nabil A., with Ahmad Ajaj, Unlawful gain and legitimate profit in Islamic law: riba, gharar, and Islamic banking. London; Boston: Graham & Trotman, 1992, 2nd ed.
- Sattar al-Harran, Saad Abdul, Islamic finance: partnership financing. Petaling Jaya, Selangor Darul Ehsan, Malaysia: Pelanduk Publications, ca. 1993.
- Shaban, S.S.A., A classified bibliography on Islamic economics. Mashad, Iran: Islamic Research Foundation, 1989.
- Shad, 'Abdur Rahman, Zakat and 'ushr. Lahore: Kazi Publications, 1986.
- Sharif, M. Raihan, The concept of economic development in Islam. Dhaka, Bangladesh: Islamic Economics Research Bureau, 1986.
- Shirazi, Habib, ed., Islamic banking. London; Boston: Butterworths, 1990.
- Siddiqi, Muhammad Nejatullah, Contemporary literature on Islamic economics: a select classified bibliography of works in English, Arabic, and Urdu up to 1975. Jeddah, Saudi Arabia: International Centre for Research on Islamic Economics, King Abdul Aziz University; Leicester [Leicestershire]: Islamic Foundation, 1978.
- Soofi, Abdol, "Economics of Ibn Khaldun revisited", History of Political Economy vol. 27 (Summer, 1995):387 (18 pages).
- Tomass, M., Review of "Ghazanfar, ed., Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the "Great Gap" in European Economics", History Of Political Economy (The MIT Press), vol. 39, n° 1, 2007, pp. 180-183.