Impediments in Developing Islamic Economics as Social Science – by Muhammad Akram Khan
For
the last three decades now, there have been significant developments in
the production of research documents, books and journal articles on
Islamic economics and finance. For example, the Harvard Islamic Finance
Project databank had by April 2014 more than 9000 records available for
free access. A number of websites and several research journals publish
material on the subject. A number of educational and training
institutions now offer courses in Islamic finance. During the last two
decades literally thousands of publications and hundreds of discussion
forums have been held on Islamic economics and finance. Despite
significant progress in terms of literature and research, Islamic
economics is yet not a social science. Generally speaking a social
science studies some social phenomenon; has a clearly defined scope and
boundary lines; and applies research methods to formulate theories for
making predictions about the future. A literature review shows that
Islamic economics does not meet the above criteria as discussed below.
We have not clearly defined the social
phenomenon that is the subject of Islamic economics. We are as yet
unclear whether economic problems as defined by conventional economics
is the focus of our study or whether we are studying some other social
phenomenon. We are uncomfortable with the expression ‘scarcity of
resources’ as it seems to flout the almightiness of God who has created
everything in abundance that human beings need. Once we deny scarcity of
resources as a fact of life, we are left with a situation which does
not have an economic problem. So, which social phenomena is the subject
of our study? We have not faced this question. The scope of Islamic
economics remains quite nebulous. The literature traverses a wide range
of subjects that includes the economic teachings of Islam as enunciated
by the Qur’an, Traditions of the Prophetand Islamic jurisprudence,
writings of scholars during the last 14 centuries, alongside subjects
like macroeconomics, microeconomics, money and banking, public finance,
microfinance, and so on. The boundaries of the subject are yet not
clearly drawn. We are also unsure about our methods of study. Some
vexing questions are as follows: (a) Should we follow, adopt or adapt
the methods of conventional economics? If yes, how to go about it? If
not, are there any distinctively Islamic methods to be used in Islamic
economics? (b) What exactly do we need to test when the primary sources
of Islamic economics are divine and have to be taken as given? (c)
How to test our hypotheses in the absence of an ideal Islamic economy?
(d) Do we assume the
existence of
homo Islamicus or
do we only theorize about ‘creating’ such a human species? We have paid
scant attention to the study of real-life conditions in the contemporary
world, although some of us think that our main business is to transform
societies to Islamic patterns. With such ambiguities about scope,
approach, objectives and methods, Islamic economics could not claim the
status of a social science.

Muhammad Akram Khan expands on the issues discussed in this post in his book ‘What is Wrong with Islam Economics?’
Impediments One problem is that we are talking to
each other to the exclusion of the wider knowledge community. This is
evident from a set of definitions presented by our colleagues. Some of
us say that we mainly study application of the
Shari’ah in economic matter. Others
think Islamic economics studies only the conditions of Muslims. Still
others require some sort of faith in Islam before a person contributes
to Islamic economics. Further, most of us often use the idioms and
jargon, the terms and phrases and the legal dicta that can be understood
easily by Muslims only. Such approaches have made Islamic economics a
branch of knowledge where Muslims are talking to Muslims. Literature on
Islamic economics presents a confused picture about the relationship
with conventional economics. One approach is to reject everything that
conventional economics offers. Another response is to develop Islamic
economics on a basis similar to conventional economics by using the
tools of the latter. Still another approach is to modify conventional
economics by incorporating ‘Islamic’ assumptions. The issue is still far
from settled. We have confused the concept of Shari’ah by mixing up
human thinking with the divine guidance. The Shari’ah consists of a
small number of clear and unambiguous injunctions stated in the
Qur’an or Traditions of the Prophet that require compliance but no
interpretation. However, we have often treated human interpretation of
these injunctions as
Shari’ah whichcreated road-blocks for
developing Islamic economics as a social science. If we treat human
thinking from the last 14 centuries as part of the
Shari’ah,
the question of formulating hypothesis and theories becomes irrelevant.
We have not rigorously reflected on the question: “What business are we
in?” Are we in the business of acquiring and developing knowledge or in
the business of transforming the society? If we are in the knowledge
business our main activity would be observation, analysis, and
reflection on divine sources and real-life facts for formulating
theories and predicting the future. However, if we are in the business
of transforming the society, we are only duplicating the effort of
thousands of religious activists and organizations already in this
business. In fact, this has been a continuous activity of religious
activists during the last 14 centuries and there is not much now to be
done through the forum of Islamic economics. We do not need to reinvent
the wheel of Islamic reformation. Some of us have attempted mathematical
modeling under conditions of the ideal Islamic society. However, the
ideal Islamic economy does not exist and will not come into being in the
foreseeable future. The assumption of the ideal Islamic society became a
stumbling block for developing Islamic economic theory. Surprisingly,
it did not occur to us that we could handle the problem from the reverse
side by asking the following question: “What will happen if the
economic units deviate from the ideal Islamic economic conditions?” Data
for such conditions were available easily around the world on almost
all economic issues. For example, we could theorize about situations
where interest was prevalent or zakah was being avoided or contracts
were not honored or property rights were not respected, etc. Proceeding
on this train of thought we could formulate hypothesis and test them in
real life. However, we did not adopt this route. Alternatively, we could
use some real-life conditions as proxies for our postulates. For
example, the orthodox position on financial interest is that it is
unlawful under Islamic law. We could take the real-life data of, for
example, Japan where the effective rate of interest has been about zero
for the several years. Similarly, we could use the real-life data of the
global effective interest-rate which has been declining for the last
three decades and is now close to zero. Using such data we could
formulate hypotheses about results of zero or near-zero rates of
interest and test them to sharpen our understanding about legality or
otherwise of the financial interest rate. However, we did not follow
this route.
For developing Islamic economics as a social science we should:
- Join forces to develop a generally accepted definition of Islamic economics.
- Couch all knowledge in general terms and on rational grounds so that it does not claim any religious sanctity.
- Make a distinction between economic teachings of Islam, which is
domain of theology, and Islamic economics which should consist of
theories derived from human understanding of the divine sources and
study of real-life conditions.
- Freely use tools of economic analysis which are the common heritage of humanity.
- Make efforts for developing generally accepted terminology.
Muhammad Akram Khan is
a Former Deputy Auditor General of Pakistan (until 2003) and Chief
Resident Auditor, UN Peacekeeping Missions (2003–2007). He took post-graduate
degrees from University of Punjab, Pakistan (1967) and Aston
University, Birmingham, UK (1970) in Commerce and Business
Administration respectively. Since 2007, he has been working as a
freelance consultant and writer whilst pursuing Islamic economics as a
private hobby. He has published 12 books, 36 research papers and over 90
book reviews. His latest book,
What is Wrong with Islamic Economics, was published in 2013; it contains a synthesis of his life-time thinking on Islamic economics and finance.